Quantitative Economics with Python
Optimal Growth III: Time Iteration
32. Optimal Growth III: Time Iteration¶
Contents
In addition to what’s in Anaconda, this lecture will need the following libraries:
!conda install -y quantecon
!pip install interpolation
Collecting package metadata (current_repodata.json): -
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
done
Solving environment: -
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
The environment is inconsistent, please check the package plan carefully
The following packages are causing the inconsistency:
- defaults/noarch::nltk==3.5=py_0
- defaults/linux-64::anaconda==2020.11=py38_0
- defaults/linux-64::scikit-learn==0.23.2=py38h0573a6f_0
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
\
|
/
-
done
## Package Plan ##
environment location: /usr/share/miniconda3/envs/lecture-python
added / updated specs:
- quantecon
The following packages will be downloaded:
package | build
---------------------------|-----------------
_anaconda_depends-2020.07 | py38_0 6 KB
anaconda-custom | py38_1 35 KB
joblib-1.0.1 | pyhd3eb1b0_0 208 KB
libllvm9-9.0.1 | h4a3c616_1 21.0 MB
quantecon-0.4.8 | py38_0 285 KB
snappy-1.1.8 | he6710b0_0 40 KB
------------------------------------------------------------
Total: 21.6 MB
The following NEW packages will be INSTALLED:
_anaconda_depends pkgs/main/linux-64::_anaconda_depends-2020.07-py38_0
joblib pkgs/main/noarch::joblib-1.0.1-pyhd3eb1b0_0
libllvm9 pkgs/main/linux-64::libllvm9-9.0.1-h4a3c616_1
quantecon pkgs/main/linux-64::quantecon-0.4.8-py38_0
snappy pkgs/main/linux-64::snappy-1.1.8-he6710b0_0
The following packages will be UPDATED:
ca-certificates 2020.10.14-0 --> 2021.1.19-h06a4308_1
certifi pkgs/main/noarch::certifi-2020.6.20-p~ --> pkgs/main/linux-64::certifi-2020.12.5-py38h06a4308_0
openssl 1.1.1h-h7b6447c_0 --> 1.1.1j-h27cfd23_0
The following packages will be DOWNGRADED:
anaconda 2020.11-py38_0 --> custom-py38_1
Downloading and Extracting Packages
anaconda-custom | 35 KB | | 0%
anaconda-custom | 35 KB | ##################################### | 100%
libllvm9-9.0.1 | 21.0 MB | | 0%
libllvm9-9.0.1 | 21.0 MB | ###########7 | 32%
libllvm9-9.0.1 | 21.0 MB | ################################### | 95%
libllvm9-9.0.1 | 21.0 MB | ##################################### | 100%
quantecon-0.4.8 | 285 KB | | 0%
quantecon-0.4.8 | 285 KB | ##################################### | 100%
joblib-1.0.1 | 208 KB | | 0%
joblib-1.0.1 | 208 KB | ##################################### | 100%
_anaconda_depends-20 | 6 KB | | 0%
_anaconda_depends-20 | 6 KB | ##################################### | 100%
snappy-1.1.8 | 40 KB | | 0%
snappy-1.1.8 | 40 KB | ##################################### | 100%
Preparing transaction: |
done
Verifying transaction: -
\
|
done
Executing transaction: -
\
|
/
-
\
done
Requirement already satisfied: interpolation in /usr/share/miniconda3/envs/lecture-python/lib/python3.8/site-packages (2.2.1)
Requirement already satisfied: numba>=0.47 in /usr/share/miniconda3/envs/lecture-python/lib/python3.8/site-packages (from interpolation) (0.51.2)
Requirement already satisfied: scipy>=1.4.1 in /usr/share/miniconda3/envs/lecture-python/lib/python3.8/site-packages (from interpolation) (1.5.2)
Requirement already satisfied: tempita>=0.5.2 in /usr/share/miniconda3/envs/lecture-python/lib/python3.8/site-packages (from interpolation) (0.5.2)
Requirement already satisfied: numpy>=1.18.1 in /usr/share/miniconda3/envs/lecture-python/lib/python3.8/site-packages (from interpolation) (1.19.2)
Requirement already satisfied: llvmlite<0.35,>=0.34.0.dev0 in /usr/share/miniconda3/envs/lecture-python/lib/python3.8/site-packages (from numba>=0.47->interpolation) (0.34.0)
Requirement already satisfied: setuptools in /usr/share/miniconda3/envs/lecture-python/lib/python3.8/site-packages (from numba>=0.47->interpolation) (50.3.1.post20201107)
32.1. Overview¶
In this lecture, we’ll continue our earlier study of the stochastic optimal growth model.
In that lecture, we solved the associated dynamic programming problem using value function iteration.
The beauty of this technique is its broad applicability.
With numerical problems, however, we can often attain higher efficiency in specific applications by deriving methods that are carefully tailored to the application at hand.
The stochastic optimal growth model has plenty of structure to exploit for this purpose, especially when we adopt some concavity and smoothness assumptions over primitives.
We’ll use this structure to obtain an Euler equation based method.
This will be an extension of the time iteration method considered in our elementary lecture on cake eating.
In a subsequent lecture, we’ll see that time iteration can be further adjusted to obtain even more efficiency.
Let’s start with some imports:
%matplotlib inline
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt
plt.rcParams["figure.figsize"] = (11, 5) #set default figure size
import numpy as np
import quantecon as qe
from interpolation import interp
from quantecon.optimize import brentq
from numba import njit, float64
from numba.experimental import jitclass
32.2. The Euler Equation¶
Our first step is to derive the Euler equation, which is a generalization of the Euler equation we obtained in the lecture on cake eating.
We take the model set out in the stochastic growth model lecture and add the following assumptions:
\(u\) and \(f\) are continuously differentiable and strictly concave
\(f(0) = 0\)
\(\lim_{c \to 0} u'(c) = \infty\) and \(\lim_{c \to \infty} u'(c) = 0\)
\(\lim_{k \to 0} f'(k) = \infty\) and \(\lim_{k \to \infty} f'(k) = 0\)
The last two conditions are usually called Inada conditions.
Recall the Bellman equation
Let the optimal consumption policy be denoted by \(\sigma^*\).
We know that \(\sigma^*\) is a \(v^*\)-greedy policy so that \(\sigma^*(y)\) is the maximizer in (32.1).
The conditions above imply that
\(\sigma^*\) is the unique optimal policy for the stochastic optimal growth model
the optimal policy is continuous, strictly increasing and also interior, in the sense that \(0 < \sigma^*(y) < y\) for all strictly positive \(y\), and
the value function is strictly concave and continuously differentiable, with
The last result is called the envelope condition due to its relationship with the envelope theorem.
To see why (32.2) holds, write the Bellman equation in the equivalent form
Differentiating with respect to \(y\), and then evaluating at the optimum yields (32.2).
(Section 12.1 of EDTC contains full proofs of these results, and closely related discussions can be found in many other texts.)
Differentiability of the value function and interiority of the optimal policy imply that optimal consumption satisfies the first order condition associated with (32.1), which is
Combining (32.2) and the first-order condition (32.3) gives the Euler equation
We can think of the Euler equation as a functional equation
over interior consumption policies \(\sigma\), one solution of which is the optimal policy \(\sigma^*\).
Our aim is to solve the functional equation (32.5) and hence obtain \(\sigma^*\).
32.2.1. The Coleman-Reffett Operator¶
Recall the Bellman operator
Just as we introduced the Bellman operator to solve the Bellman equation, we will now introduce an operator over policies to help us solve the Euler equation.
This operator \(K\) will act on the set of all \(\sigma \in \Sigma\) that are continuous, strictly increasing and interior.
Henceforth we denote this set of policies by \(\mathscr P\)
The operator \(K\) takes as its argument a \(\sigma \in \mathscr P\) and
returns a new function \(K\sigma\), where \(K\sigma(y)\) is the \(c \in (0, y)\) that solves.
We call this operator the Coleman-Reffett operator to acknowledge the work of [Col90] and [Ref96].
In essence, \(K\sigma\) is the consumption policy that the Euler equation tells you to choose today when your future consumption policy is \(\sigma\).
The important thing to note about \(K\) is that, by construction, its fixed points coincide with solutions to the functional equation (32.5).
In particular, the optimal policy \(\sigma^*\) is a fixed point.
Indeed, for fixed \(y\), the value \(K\sigma^*(y)\) is the \(c\) that solves
In view of the Euler equation, this is exactly \(\sigma^*(y)\).
32.2.2. Is the Coleman-Reffett Operator Well Defined?¶
In particular, is there always a unique \(c \in (0, y)\) that solves (32.7)?
The answer is yes, under our assumptions.
For any \(\sigma \in \mathscr P\), the right side of (32.7)
is continuous and strictly increasing in \(c\) on \((0, y)\)
diverges to \(+\infty\) as \(c \uparrow y\)
The left side of (32.7)
is continuous and strictly decreasing in \(c\) on \((0, y)\)
diverges to \(+\infty\) as \(c \downarrow 0\)
Sketching these curves and using the information above will convince you that they cross exactly once as \(c\) ranges over \((0, y)\).
With a bit more analysis, one can show in addition that \(K \sigma \in \mathscr P\) whenever \(\sigma \in \mathscr P\).
32.2.3. Comparison with VFI (Theory)¶
It is possible to prove that there is a tight relationship between iterates of \(K\) and iterates of the Bellman operator.
Mathematically, the two operators are topologically conjugate.
Loosely speaking, this means that if iterates of one operator converge then so do iterates of the other, and vice versa.
Moreover, there is a sense in which they converge at the same rate, at least in theory.
However, it turns out that the operator \(K\) is more stable numerically and hence more efficient in the applications we consider.
Examples are given below.
32.3. Implementation¶
As in our previous study, we continue to assume that
\(u(c) = \ln c\)
\(f(k) = k^{\alpha}\)
\(\phi\) is the distribution of \(\xi := \exp(\mu + s \zeta)\) when \(\zeta\) is standard normal
This will allow us to compare our results to the analytical solutions
def v_star(y, α, β, μ):
"""
True value function
"""
c1 = np.log(1 - α * β) / (1 - β)
c2 = (μ + α * np.log(α * β)) / (1 - α)
c3 = 1 / (1 - β)
c4 = 1 / (1 - α * β)
return c1 + c2 * (c3 - c4) + c4 * np.log(y)
def σ_star(y, α, β):
"""
True optimal policy
"""
return (1 - α * β) * y
As discussed above, our plan is to solve the model using time iteration, which means iterating with the operator \(K\).
For this we need access to the functions \(u'\) and \(f, f'\).
These are available in a class called OptimalGrowthModel
that we
constructed in an earlier lecture.
opt_growth_data = [
('α', float64), # Production parameter
('β', float64), # Discount factor
('μ', float64), # Shock location parameter
('s', float64), # Shock scale parameter
('grid', float64[:]), # Grid (array)
('shocks', float64[:]) # Shock draws (array)
]
@jitclass(opt_growth_data)
class OptimalGrowthModel:
def __init__(self,
α=0.4,
β=0.96,
μ=0,
s=0.1,
grid_max=4,
grid_size=120,
shock_size=250,
seed=1234):
self.α, self.β, self.μ, self.s = α, β, μ, s
# Set up grid
self.grid = np.linspace(1e-5, grid_max, grid_size)
# Store shocks (with a seed, so results are reproducible)
np.random.seed(seed)
self.shocks = np.exp(μ + s * np.random.randn(shock_size))
def f(self, k):
"The production function"
return k**self.α
def u(self, c):
"The utility function"
return np.log(c)
def f_prime(self, k):
"Derivative of f"
return self.α * (k**(self.α - 1))
def u_prime(self, c):
"Derivative of u"
return 1/c
def u_prime_inv(self, c):
"Inverse of u'"
return 1/c
Now we implement a method called euler_diff
, which returns
@njit
def euler_diff(c, σ, y, og):
"""
Set up a function such that the root with respect to c,
given y and σ, is equal to Kσ(y).
"""
β, shocks, grid = og.β, og.shocks, og.grid
f, f_prime, u_prime = og.f, og.f_prime, og.u_prime
# First turn σ into a function via interpolation
σ_func = lambda x: interp(grid, σ, x)
# Now set up the function we need to find the root of.
vals = u_prime(σ_func(f(y - c) * shocks)) * f_prime(y - c) * shocks
return u_prime(c) - β * np.mean(vals)
The function euler_diff
evaluates integrals by Monte Carlo and
approximates functions using linear interpolation.
We will use a root-finding algorithm to solve (32.8) for \(c\) given state \(y\) and \(σ\), the current guess of the policy.
Here’s the operator \(K\), that implements the root-finding step.
@njit
def K(σ, og):
"""
The Coleman-Reffett operator
Here og is an instance of OptimalGrowthModel.
"""
β = og.β
f, f_prime, u_prime = og.f, og.f_prime, og.u_prime
grid, shocks = og.grid, og.shocks
σ_new = np.empty_like(σ)
for i, y in enumerate(grid):
# Solve for optimal c at y
c_star = brentq(euler_diff, 1e-10, y-1e-10, args=(σ, y, og))[0]
σ_new[i] = c_star
return σ_new
32.3.1. Testing¶
Let’s generate an instance and plot some iterates of \(K\), starting from \(σ(y) = y\).
og = OptimalGrowthModel()
grid = og.grid
n = 15
σ = grid.copy() # Set initial condition
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
lb = 'initial condition $\sigma(y) = y$'
ax.plot(grid, σ, color=plt.cm.jet(0), alpha=0.6, label=lb)
for i in range(n):
σ = K(σ, og)
ax.plot(grid, σ, color=plt.cm.jet(i / n), alpha=0.6)
# Update one more time and plot the last iterate in black
σ = K(σ, og)
ax.plot(grid, σ, color='k', alpha=0.8, label='last iterate')
ax.legend()
plt.show()
We see that the iteration process converges quickly to a limit that resembles the solution we obtained in the previous lecture.
Here is a function called solve_model_time_iter
that takes an instance of
OptimalGrowthModel
and returns an approximation to the optimal policy,
using time iteration.
def solve_model_time_iter(model, # Class with model information
σ, # Initial condition
tol=1e-4,
max_iter=1000,
verbose=True,
print_skip=25):
# Set up loop
i = 0
error = tol + 1
while i < max_iter and error > tol:
σ_new = K(σ, model)
error = np.max(np.abs(σ - σ_new))
i += 1
if verbose and i % print_skip == 0:
print(f"Error at iteration {i} is {error}.")
σ = σ_new
if i == max_iter:
print("Failed to converge!")
if verbose and i < max_iter:
print(f"\nConverged in {i} iterations.")
return σ_new
Let’s call it:
σ_init = np.copy(og.grid)
σ = solve_model_time_iter(og, σ_init)
Converged in 11 iterations.
Here is a plot of the resulting policy, compared with the true policy:
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
ax.plot(og.grid, σ, lw=2,
alpha=0.8, label='approximate policy function')
ax.plot(og.grid, σ_star(og.grid, og.α, og.β), 'k--',
lw=2, alpha=0.8, label='true policy function')
ax.legend()
plt.show()
Again, the fit is excellent.
The maximal absolute deviation between the two policies is
np.max(np.abs(σ - σ_star(og.grid, og.α, og.β)))
2.5329106213334285e-05
How long does it take to converge?
%%timeit -n 3 -r 1
σ = solve_model_time_iter(og, σ_init, verbose=False)
190 ms ± 0 ns per loop (mean ± std. dev. of 1 run, 3 loops each)
Convergence is very fast, even compared to our JIT-compiled value function iteration.
Overall, we find that time iteration provides a very high degree of efficiency and accuracy, at least for this model.
32.4. Exercises¶
32.4.1. Exercise 1¶
Solve the model with CRRA utility
Set γ = 1.5
.
Compute and plot the optimal policy.
32.5. Solutions¶
32.5.1. Exercise 1¶
We use the class OptimalGrowthModel_CRRA
from our VFI lecture.
opt_growth_data = [
('α', float64), # Production parameter
('β', float64), # Discount factor
('μ', float64), # Shock location parameter
('γ', float64), # Preference parameter
('s', float64), # Shock scale parameter
('grid', float64[:]), # Grid (array)
('shocks', float64[:]) # Shock draws (array)
]
@jitclass(opt_growth_data)
class OptimalGrowthModel_CRRA:
def __init__(self,
α=0.4,
β=0.96,
μ=0,
s=0.1,
γ=1.5,
grid_max=4,
grid_size=120,
shock_size=250,
seed=1234):
self.α, self.β, self.γ, self.μ, self.s = α, β, γ, μ, s
# Set up grid
self.grid = np.linspace(1e-5, grid_max, grid_size)
# Store shocks (with a seed, so results are reproducible)
np.random.seed(seed)
self.shocks = np.exp(μ + s * np.random.randn(shock_size))
def f(self, k):
"The production function."
return k**self.α
def u(self, c):
"The utility function."
return c**(1 - self.γ) / (1 - self.γ)
def f_prime(self, k):
"Derivative of f."
return self.α * (k**(self.α - 1))
def u_prime(self, c):
"Derivative of u."
return c**(-self.γ)
def u_prime_inv(c):
return c**(-1 / self.γ)
Let’s create an instance:
og_crra = OptimalGrowthModel_CRRA()
Now we solve and plot the policy:
%%time
σ = solve_model_time_iter(og_crra, σ_init)
fig, ax = plt.subplots()
ax.plot(og.grid, σ, lw=2,
alpha=0.8, label='approximate policy function')
ax.legend()
plt.show()
Converged in 13 iterations.
CPU times: user 2.09 s, sys: 11.9 ms, total: 2.11 s
Wall time: 2.11 s